Sourcing the Right Crowd

Commercialization is rarely a solitary pursuit; bringing an idea to the world requires a set of diverse skills and knowledge, a proverbial commercialization village. Or a crowd. Enter the power of crowdsourcing.

Crowdsourcing refers to aggregating a large number of people to express their opinions or ideas about specific topics—and the term first appeared in a 2006 Wired magazine article by Jeff Howe. But simply bringing together a large number of people is not enough to create new products. An integral part of engaging a large community to solve the world’s biggest problems is matching the right type of crowd to two stages of the commercialization process: a diverse crowd for brainstorming of breakthrough innovations, and a large crowd for refining the product for the market.

By its definition, innovation requires a break with the status quo. Research repeatedly shows that groups with diverse backgrounds propose the largest number of unique solutions to a problem. This has also been my experience with BrainBuzzes, brainstorming events that I organize for Young Inventors International. The simplest explanation for this phenomenon arises from research by James March and the late Nobel Laureate and Turing Award winner Herbert Simon, who suggest that our capacity to search for solutions is limited by what we know. Thus, we find solutions that are “locally” optimal to what we know, but which may not be “globally” optimal for innovation because we are restricted in our search space. By bringing together a diverse group of people, we end up expanding the search field for increasingly “global” solutions and drawing on expertise from unrelated fields. While a larger number of people can brainstorm more solutions, diversity is key when crowdsourcing new, breakthrough product ideas.

One of the most established Internet companies that uses crowdsourcing to assist with brainstorming is Innocentive. Innocentive brings together companies that post problems for scientists and engineers around the world; the winning solution receives a specified amount of prize money. Innocentive focuses on brainstorming new breakthrough solutions; its model allows the company to provide economic opportunities to a diverse group of researchers from outside of North America whose experiences may be different from those of their North American colleagues. Another web site, Innovation Exchange, works on a similar premise, although it also allows for collaboration among problem solvers.

However, the success of an innovation depends not only on its ingenuity but also on its appeal to and adoption by the market. The market is perilous and fickle, and the products that are most likely to succeed are those that are best able to anticipate and satisfy the needs of the largest number of customers. For many years, marketing experts have used focus groups of potential customers to assist with identifying issues of usefulness and usability of new products. Today, the Internet allows for relatively easy aggregation of large numbers of people who can provide feedback on a product or vote on the optimal solution. The number of participants matters more in this case. Indeed, the ideal crowd to source is one comprising of all potential customers.

Other companies in the space include Cambrian House, Kluster, IdeaScale, CrowdSpirit, FellowForce, and IdeaBlob. All of these companies incorporate elements of voting for the best ideas. But to arrive at the wisdom of the crowd, the sites require large amounts of traffic. As more of these sites arise, there is a battle for users and, unless there are incentives for participants to contribute, these communities may suffer. For product refinement and focus group crowdsourcing, the best model might be for companies to encourage feedback on their own web site, such as Dell does through its Idea Storm site and Salesforce does through its Idea Exchange. This model is likely to generate better results because the companies already receive large amounts of traffic interested in their products and participants can be rewarded with free products or product discounts relevant to their interests.

While giving away products, discounts, or flat fees might suffice as compensation for focus group participants, determining sufficient compensation for innovators who create truly disruptive ideas with breakthrough market potential is more difficult. If correct incentives do not exist to compensate participants for their contribution of intellectual property, those with the most promising ideas will choose to commercialize them on their own. Understanding the type of group that must be sourced for a specific purpose allows us to begin designing rewards that will attract the right crowd essential to the complex journey of commercialization.

Author: Anne Swift

Anne is passionate about marketing, entrepreneurship, and collaborative innovation systems. Glamour Magazine named Anne a visionary who will change the world for her work with Young Inventors International. As the founder of Young Inventors, Anne has trained more than 3,000 university innovators around the world, at institutions such as MIT, Carnegie Mellon University, University of Wisconsin at Madison, and Northeastern University. Under Anne’s leadership, Young Inventors held conferences at MIT, Carnegie Mellon, and the University of Toronto. She is the pioneer of BrainBuzz, a structured methodology for using collaborating teams to solve technology challenges at institutions such as MIT's Innovations in International Health and the Ashoka Foundation. Currently, Anne is the Head of Marketing (a.k.a. Chief Marketing Nut) at Nuts.com. In early 2008, Anne co-founded a solar thermal building materials start-up, which installed the largest, and award-winning, solar thermal project in Pennsylvania. Anne has also consulted for the MaRS Discovery District, the Cleantech Venture Network, and technology start-up companies, including many social ventures. She has been a judge of several business plan competitions, including the MIT IDEAS Competition, the Stanford BASES Competition, Ashoka-Lemelson Invention Competition, and San Jose State University’s Neat Ideas Fair. With training as an economist, Anne has conducted research on how organizations can successfully work together to identify and commercialize innovations, as well as how innovations arise in collaborative group settings. Anne’s work included research positions with the Innovation Systems Research Network at the University of Toronto and Carnegie Mellon University with support from the Kauffman Foundation. Anne also holds certificates from the World Intellectual Property Organization in intellectual property and management of innovation. Anne’s work has appeared in Science Magazine, IEEE Spectrum, Forbes, Popular Science, NPR, and many other major media outlets. For more information about Anne’s background, please visit www.anneswift.com.